Hollywood Course on Wall Street–Better than any MBA!?

Working on Wall StreetMargin Call: http://youtu.be/0rqofLr9HE0

The way to make money on Wall Street- Margin Call: http://youtu.be/xOO1NY6ctYU

You are getting fired-Margin Call: http://youtu.be/2f2kGHcdJYU

Danny Devito as Ben Graham in Other People’s Money, “Show me the numbers.” http://youtu.be/yypj-aYtp9c

Danny Devito as “Larry the Liquidator” says, “I’m NOT your best friend, I am your ONLY friend” http://youtu.be/p7rvupKipmY

Boiler Room: “RECO!” http://youtu.be/4zakyg3thfY You could do a thesis on all the psychological ploys used to make this sale.  Also, http://youtu.be/izOIOvguncU  Always be closing!

Wall Street: “Because it’s wreckable.”http://youtu.be/2Mr4mjeZ2ko

Trading Places: Learning about commodities: http://youtu.be/7EjdC0pjo1A

Valuation Study in Trading Places, “Well, in Philadelphia, it is worth 50 bucks: http://youtu.be/jLo7tHDHgOc

Auction market: http://youtu.be/uZ94J09IsHA

Trading Soybeans (How would you like to do THAT all day?) http://youtu.be/XZEBz01t5vg

In those short clips you will grasp more than many beginning MBAs of how the world works.  Good luck!

Appendix: Comment: A movie like this is not a sign of a Bull Market. The movie reflects and/or caters to the Public’s disgust with Wall Street.

| SATURDAY, SEPTEMBER 8, 2012

Wall Street Meets Hollywood. Greed Ensues.

By MARTIN FRIDSON | MORE ARTICLES BY AUTHOR

A review of the new Richard Gere vehicle, Arbitrage, in which a wealthy hedge-fund manager is—surprise—the villain. Suggestion to the filmmakers: Check the dictionary before you title your next movie.

“Arbitrage—buying low and selling high—depends on a person’s ability to determine the true value of any given market,” reads the program note for the Sundance Film Festival, where writer-director Nicholas Jarecki’s movie Arbitrage was screened to rousing acclaim in January.

From the start, then, someone got the definition wrong. Whoever wrote that program note apparently believes arbitrage—simultaneously buying and selling the same asset at difference prices—is just another form of value investing (“buying low and selling high”).

Call me a purist, but if you pay good money to watch a movie called Arbitrage, you should get to see a little of it. Arbitrage depicts nobody in the act of arbitrage. Not that this would be the first time title and content diverge. At least the hedge-fund manager in Arbitrage does engage in hedging (laying off risk), unlike some real-life firms that call themselves hedge funds without actually hedging.

image

If Arbitrage were a bond, it would make investment grade, but just barely.

Richard Gere stars as Robert Miller, a successful hedge-fund manager who illegally covers up a $400 million loss, then attempts to escape the consequences by selling his company. The sale becomes more difficult when he commits another crime in the course of a bit of wife-cheating with a sexy art dealer. That leads to a second coverup and to a breach with his adoring and idealistic daughter, who is also the firm’s chief investment officer.

Compared with other films on finance worth seeing—admittedly, a short list—Arbitrage fails to give the stock market a pivotal role. Director Oliver Stone’s Wall Street, which features Michael Douglas as takeover artist Gordon Gekko, creates tension with a takeover battle. That film also shows protagonist Charlie Sheen breaking the insider-trading laws instead of just telling the audience about it.

In Boiler Room, the most engrossing action consists of penny-stock salesmen conning their victims. By contrast, Gere’s Robert Miller has already committed his financial crime by the time the action begins.

It might be objected that Arbitrage would lose the average moviegoer by dwelling on the details of securities transactions. But the excellent finance film Margin Call, which does depict margin calls, manages to convey the essential facts about complex derivatives to a general audience. By declining the challenge of portraying finance on-screen, Arbitrage becomes a film as much about its peripheral subjects—police work, the art world, and philanthropy—as the stock market.

BEYOND BEING MISNAMED, the film lacks one key ingredient of the most enduring investment-oriented movies: an instantly quotable line. Wall Street had “Greed is good.” The cult favorite Boiler Room had “You got a cannoli you can stick in your mouth?”—followed by a rejoinder that is not printable in a family magazine. The best Arbitrage can offer is this response to the observation that it’s a cold world: “You’d better get a warm coat.”

The Bottom Line

In addition to being a thriller with few thrills, Arbitrage even bungles the meaning of its title. Wait for this one to come to cable.

But hey, this is a movie: Whether or not Arbitrage holds up as a finance film, is it a decent popcorn picture that spins a suspenseful yarn? It benefits from some good acting. Richard Gere is more than adequate in the lead. Susan Sarandon, already experienced at playing Gere’s long-suffering wife (in Shall We Dance?), again fulfills that duty with finesse. Tim Roth and Nate Parker shine in supporting roles. CNBC’s Maria Bartiromo plays Maria Bartiromo in a cameo that adds luster to the proceedings.

Key plot twists are at times cleverly foreshadowed. Characters reveal unexpected depth as they confront not-so-easy moral choices. A tearful embrace that occurs at a funeral is a powerful use of dramatic irony, and the story’s resolution denies viewers any smug satisfaction that all’s well that ends well.

But these individual touches are too infrequent. If Arbitrage were a bond, it would make investment grade, but just barely.

This shortfall raises the question of why Arbitrage garnered such raves at Sundance, even spurring talk of an Oscar for Richard Gere. The critics’ huzzahs are hard to explain on purely cinematic grounds. As an exploration of family betrayal, Arbitrage is no more than workmanlike. Unlike the best thrillers, it will leave most stomachs unknotted.

THE SUNDANCE CRITICS WERE probably won over by writer-director Jarecki’s choice of a fashionable political theme, the 1% versus the 99%. And you can never go wrong in Hollywood by making the businessman the villain.

Gere’s Robert Miller stands a good chance of prevailing over the law-enforcement system, thanks to his immense wealth, unlike the working-class youth he draws into his crime, played by Nate Parker. The detective, played by Tim Roth, who pursues Miller openly complains that he is in an unfair fight if he must pursue such a privileged perpetrator without having license to fake the evidence. To compound the corruption at the top, we learn that Miller cut corners even in the supposedly lawful phase of building his fortune.

Arbitrage will be released in theatres Friday, Sept. 14. Will media critics also be seduced by the film’s populist theme, or will they judge it according to more rigorous standards of movie-making? That question is as suspenseful as anything you’re likely to see in Arbitrage.

MARTIN FRIDSON is the global credit strategist and CEO of FridsonVision.  He reviewed the film version of Atlas Shrugged last year.

The Old Man and the Tree: A Parable of Valuation; Back to School; and More…

Back to School

Back to school (a classic!) http://youtu.be/YlVDGmjz7eM

Any Columbia Graduate Business School Students attending this–Course on Mental Models and Investment Frameworks? Mental Models Columbia GBS 2012 Syllabus

A Preview to be read for the See’s Case Study (forthcoming….)

The Old Man and the Tree: A Parable of Valuation

Adapted from Solomon, Schwartz & Bauman,
Corporations – Cases and Materials at 143 (3d ed. 1996).

*****

Once there was an old, wise man who owned an apple tree. It was a fine tree. With modest care it yielded a crop of apples which he sold for $100 each year. The man wanted money for new pursuits and thought of selling the tree. So, hoping to teach a good lesson, he placed an ad in the Business Opportunities section of the Wall Street Journal: “For sale, apple tree – best offer.”

The Old Man and the Tree or a Parable of Valuation

Readings and Viewing

http://blog.marketpsych.com/ and http://www.marketpsych.com/blog.php

Do not criticize the government (Marine sent to mental ward): http://www.lewrockwell.com/lewrockwell-show/2012/08/24/303-psycho-state-targeted-brandon-raub/

HAVE A GREAT WEEKEND!

What Can We Learn from IBM?

PS: I may not post the See’s Candies case study until tomorrow….backed up with work. Until then, tackle this:

Why did Buffett buy IBM?

IBM_VL    Don’t cheat! Look at the Value-Line and write what Buffett sees in IBM. (Disclosure: I own IBM along with BDX, BCR, CSCO, LXK, NVS, TESCO, ORI, etc. and I will not announce if and when I sell. I may be incorrect in the assessment of those businesses either in price paid or assessment of value.)

What do you think of IBM’s growth? Is this a good business? What might be driving returns for shareholders? How would you classify this company?  A rapid compounder? Value trap?

How can a company as well-known as IBM become mis-priced?

Hint: For those who wish to start your own fund….research the studies on horse track betting where favorites are SYSTEMATICALLY under-bet (under priced) while long shots are SYSTEMATICALLY over bet or over priced.

Notes:

Betting on Favorites

See research:Favorite_Longshot_Bias

http://www.gogerty.com/blogpersonal/2012/09/

One of the common criticisms I (Investor lecture at Columbia GBS) hear about this type of investing is that it is akin to betting on favorites at the race track. Once you have identified a company that is so obviously superior, how likely is it to be undervalued since the whole world will have perceived that it is an extraordinary company? The stock won’t have a margin of safety and may be persistently over-valued. The stock may be over-loved and overvalued.

Let me back up a second. As part of my misspent youth, I spent a lot of time in horse racing and handicapping. In fact, bettors in aggregate in pari-mutual betting are, in fact, very good at picking winners at the racetrack. Favorites do win races. But betting on favorites does not make you money; it loses you the least amount of money. Because there is a tremendous track take. So the horse racing/handicapping is a minus 20 percent on typical betting. If you just put money down on favorites as a mechanical system, the record shows that you will lose over time only 2%, 3% or 4%. If you bet on long shots, you will lose 20+% of your money.

Now in the case of the stock market over a long period of time, it has been a plus 9, plus 10, plus 11% game so it is very much more favorable business than horse betting. But betting on favorites, betting on quality as opposed to junk is a winning bet, as long as the valuation discipline is appropriate.

Prize awarded: Boom, Gloom, and Doom Report for the BEST reply.

Ok, now take a look at these articles: http://tech.fortune.cnn.com/2011/11/14/warren-buffett-ibm/

and  http://seekingalpha.com/article/510371-what-does-warren-buffett-see-in-ibm

Lessons learned?

If I can stress anything–and it took me TEN years to learn and I fall off the wagon occasionally–keep things simple!

Expectations for Growth, Agricultural Prices

The Count of Oropesa, more than four and a half centuries ago had a passion to reform the world. A Spanish saint, San Pedro of Alcantara, gave him the kind of counsel I am urging on everyone who would advance Liberty.

May your Lordship not torment yourself: there is a remedy for this deluge of crimes. Let us be, you and me, that which we should be. There will be two less souls to convert. Let each person behave thus: it is the most efficacious of reforms. The trouble is, that no one wants to correct himself and everyone meddles at correcting others: thus everything stays as is. –Leonard Read

LMCM August  Note page 6 on future expectations.

Agricultural Prices  Where money is going…

Excess Reserves: The key is not what banks put excess reserves in, but that they are moved out of excess reserves. Remember, excess reserves are funds
sitting at the Fed and not in the system. Even if banks take the money
out of excess reserves and buy Treasury bills, they are buying the
bills from someone and thus putting the money in the system. This is
what will cause the price inflation, even if T-bill rates go down
short-term. Bottom line: If enough money comes out of excess reserves,
the price inflation will be huge. Remember, there is more than $1.5
trillion sitting there.   (Watch for Bank lending growth)

—www.economicpolicyjournal.com

 

 

Poverty Amidst Splendor or Lessons in Tyranny. Alexander Roepers, Activist Investor

There is very little the privileged class has that everyone else doesn’t have, except money.–Alex Castro (son of Fidel Castro)

Tremeda Hambre! http://youtu.be/ssIv2c-u7R0  This Cuban interrupts an interview with a Cuban Reggae artist, yelling that he is hungry.  He represents life in Cuba for the majority.

Life in Cuba for the masses:http://www.therealcuba.com/Videos.htm. Grim.

Of course, for a dictator to impoverish his country to desperation while holding onto power, there must be a special few to keep him in power.

Splendor amidst poverty with Cuba’s Gilded Elite http://www.theatlantic.com/international/archive/2012/09/splendor-amid-poverty-gallery-nights-with-cubas-gilded-elite/261956/

To understand how to take and hold power, read Machievelli http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Niccol%C3%B2_Machiavelli and my recent favorite:

And for more detail, The dictator’s handbook and blog (Satire!): http://dictatorshandbook.net/

Lessons for investors

Why bother? Well, those lessons will illuminate why and how there are so few gifted CEOs but so many highly paid CEOs with miniscule tie to performance in corporate America (though the situation is better than in Japan). Packed, insider boards and benchmarking with diffuse, ignorant shareholders might be the some of the reasons.

Pay for Performance Puzzle: http://www.businessweek.com/investor/content/sep2009/pi20090923_783858.htm

Please be in touch if any of you become a tyrant in a small, hot country.

Alexander Roepers

http://greenbackd.com/2012/09/05/alexander-roepers-gentleman-activist/

Visit www.greenbackd.com for discounts to this year’s Value Investors Conference.

What is Wrong with Austrian Economics? 1873 and 2008; The Future in Glass; See’s Candies Case Study

“If a man has a talent and cannot use it, he has failed. If he has a talent and uses only half of it, he has partly failed. If he has a talent and learns somehow to use the whole of it, he has gloriously succeeded, and won a satisfaction and a triumph few men ever know.” — Thomas Wolfe

“Work is love made visible. And if you cannot work with love but only with distaste, it is better that you should leave your work and sit at the gate of the temple and take alms of those who work with joy.” –Kahlil Gibran

SUGAR: last mentioned http://wp.me/p1PgpH-1dr. Have a jelly donut:http://youtu.be/OhhJwJbYruA

The Future?

A day made of glass: Part 1: http://youtu.be/6Cf7IL_eZ38 Part 2: http://youtu.be/jZkHpNnXLB0

See’s Candies last discussed here: http://wp.me/p1PgpH-1bZ.

Readers did a fine job of analyzing why Buffett paid 3xs tangible book value. While cleaning out old files I came across a discussion of See’s that perhaps not many have seen, so I will post tomorrow.

What is Wrong with the Austrians?

Before you can know what is “wrong” with Austrian Business Cycle Theory (“ABCT”), you need to know about the theory.

A ten lecture series on Austrian Economic Analysis: http://mises.org/media/categories/89/Introduction-to-Austrian-Economic-Analysis

The Austrian School: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Austrian_School

As a history fanatic, I am enjoying A Nation of Deadbeats: An Uncommon History of America’s Financial Disasters by Scott Reynolds Nelson. 

More on the author here:http://www.wm.edu/research/ideation/social-sciences/economic-deja-vu6543.php

The book’s author has studied the Austrian approach but finds fault with it. He weaves an interesting account of the Panics of 1792, 1819, 1837, 1857, 1873, 1907, 1920 and 1929. He says government can’t be entirely to blame for some of the overleveraging, fraud and mal-investment of the booms that lead to busts.  I lack historical knowledge to completely grasp his arguments, but after finishing this book I will take another crack.  I do believe that understanding where leverage has built up is crucial to understanding the effects of the bust. For example, the Internet boom occurred mostly in equities while the 2008 credit crisis developed in the banking system. Banking panics will most likely be much more severe due to the high (at least 10 to 1) leverage in our banking system. The credit contraction is quick to spread throughout the economy. The Internet bust primarily caused a bust in Internet and Telcom companies’ stock prices.

The Panic of 1873 as a model to understand 2008

The best model to understand the 2008 Crisis was the 1873 panic NOT 1929.

The author: “Everyone was talking about 1929, but I said in this article that the depression following the Panic of 1873 was much more like our current crash than 1929,” Nelson said. “1873 was a mortgage meltdown, then bank failure, which then led to stock market collapse.”

http://srnels.people.wm.edu/articles/realGrtDepr.html

Scott Nelson 1873 and 2008 and below are original source documents from the period. NYT on Panic of 1873, 

Workers Riot in NYC 1874

Speculation Rampant in RR in 1873

Problems with Austrian Business Cycle Theory

Another historian’s view: Jeffrey Hummel Arguments against ABCT

I will seek out the contra-arguments to Austrian theory as a way to better understand the strengths and weaknesses of various economic theories and approaches. Is Austrian theory perfect? I don’t believe so, but it has been the best construct for me to understand how booms develop and end–so far.  What do YOU think?

Business cycle theory

According to most mainstream economists, the Austrian business cycle theory is incorrect.[33]

Some mainstream economists argue that the Austrian business cycle theory requires bankers and investors to exhibit a kind of irrationality, because their theory requires bankers to be regularly fooled into making unprofitable investments by temporarily low interest rates.[5][24][117] In response, historian Thomas Woods argues that few bankers and investors are familiar enough with the Austrian business cycle theory to consistently make sound investment decisions. Austrian economists Anthony Carilli and Gregory Dempster argue that a banker or firm loses market share if it does not borrow or loan at a magnitude consistent with current interest rates, regardless of whether rates are below their natural levels. Thus businesses are forced to operate as though rates were set appropriately, because the consequence of a single entity deviating would be a loss of business.[95] Austrian economist Robert Murphy argues that it is difficult for bankers and investors to make sound business choices because they cannot know what the interest rate would be if it were set by the market.[97] Austrian economist Sean Rosenthal argues that widespread knowledge of the Austrian business cycle theory increases the amount of malinvestment during periods of artificially low interest rates.[118]

Economist Paul Krugman has argued that the theory cannot explain changes in unemployment over the business cycle. Austrian business cycle theory postulates that business cycles are caused by the misallocation of resources from consumption to investment during “booms”, and out of investment during “busts”. Krugman argues that because total spending is equal to total income in an economy, the theory implies that the reallocation of resources during “busts” would increase employment in consumption industries, whereas in reality, spending declines in all sectors of an economy during recessions. He also argues that according to the theory the initial “booms” would also cause resource reallocation, which implies an increase in unemployment during booms as well.[28] In response, Austrian economist David Gordon argues that Krugman’s argument is dependent on a misrepresentation of the theory. He furthermore argues that prices on consumption goods may go up as a result of the investment bust, which could mean that the amount spent on consumption could increase even though the quantity of goods consumed has not.[119] Furthermore, Roger Garrison argues that a false boom caused by artificially low interest rates would cause a boom in consumption goods as well as investment goods (with a decrease in “middle goods”) thus explaining the jump in unemployment at the end of a boom.[120] Many Austrians also argue that capital allocated to investment goods cannot be quickly augmented to create consumption goods.[121]

Economist Jeffery Hummel is critical of Hayek’s explanation of labor asymmetry in booms and busts. He argues that Hayek makes peculiar assumptions about demand curves for labor in his explanation of how a decrease in investment spending creates unemployment. He also argues that the labor asymmetry can be explained in terms of a change in real wages, but this explanation fails to explain the business cycle in terms of resource allocation.[122]

Hummel also argues that the Austrian explanation of the business cycle fails on empirical grounds. In particular, he notes that investment spending remained positive in all recessions where there are data, except for the Great Depression. He argues that this casts doubt on the notion that recessions are caused by a reallocation of resources from industrial production to consumption, since he argues that the Austrian business cycle theory implies that net investment should be below zero during recessions.[122] In response, Austrian economist Walter Block argues that the misallocation during booms does not preclude the possibility of demand increasing overall.[123]

Critics have also argued that, as the Austrian business cycle theory points to the actions of fractional-reserve banks and central banks to explain the business cycles, it fails to explain the severity of business cycles before the establishment of the Federal Reserve in 1913.[33] Supporters of the Austrian business cycle theory respond that the theory applies to the expansion of the money supply, not necessarily an expansion done by a central bank.[124] Historian Thomas Woods argues that the crashes were caused by various privately-owned banks with state charters that issued paper money, supposedly convertible to gold, in amounts greatly exceeding their gold reserves.[125]

In 1969, economist Milton Friedman, after examining the history of business cycles in the U.S., concluded that “The Hayek-Mises explanation of the business cycle is contradicted by the evidence. It is, I believe, false.”[26] He analyzed the issue using newer data in 1993, and again reached the same conclusion.[27] Austrian economist Jesus Huerta de Soto argued that Friedman’s conclusions are based on misleading data (such as GDP).[124] Austrian economist Roger Garrison argued that Friedman misinterpreted economic aggregates and how they related to the business cycles he reviewed.[126]

END

Is Sugar Toxic?

OriginalPost:

http://www.onlinenursingprograms.com/nursing-your-sweet-tooth/

What to do: http://articles.mercola.com/sites/articles/archive/2011/07/26/what-caused-america-to-go-from-fit-to-fat.aspx

Resources for Beginning Value Investors

Below are resources on Value Investing and Behavioral Finance from  http://www.safalniveshak.com/about-safal-niveshak You can also sign up for his free newsletter.  That blog might give beginners a more programmed approach to learning the philosophy of value investing. See for yourself.  For old pros you have probably seen many of the articles below but just in case…..

Benjamin Graham
Conversation with Benjamin Graham
Should Rich But Losing Corporations Be Liquidated
Should Rich Corporations Return Stockholders Cash
Security Analysts Rating
Stock Dividends
Stock Dividends-Part 2
Money As Pure Commodity
Lectures of Benjamin Graham
An Hour With Ben Graham
Stock Market Warning
Valuation of Common Stocks
Valuation of Common Stocks–2
How to Handle Your Money
Interpretation of Financial Statements
The Future of Common Stocks

Warren Buffett
Warren Buffett’s Letters to Berkshire Shareholders
Warren Buffett’s Partnership Letters (1957-70)
Superinvestors of Graham & Doddsville
Warren Buffett Letters on Walter Schloss
Warren Buffett on Derivatives
How Inflation Swindles the Equity Investor
Security I Like Best
Warning About the Use of Derivatives

Charlie Munger
Lesson on Elementary, Worldly Wisdom
Psychology of Human Misjudgment

Seth Klarman
Seth Klarman’s Baupost Group Letters
Who to Blame When the Market Drops
Painful Decision to Hold Cash
Risk and Productive Worrying
Guide to Choose a Money Manager
Why Value Investors are Different
Opportunities for Patient Investors
Notes to Margin of Safety
The Value of Not Being Sure
Lecture on Value Investing at MIT
Risk and “Productive Worrying”

Walter Schloss
Lecture on Value Investing
Factors Needed to Make Money in Stock Market
Experience
Sixty-Five Years on Wall Street

Prof. Sanjay Bakshi
Confessions of a Value Investor
Understanding the Universe of the Unknown and the Unknowable
Archives of Articles & Talks
Fundoo Professor Blog

Miscellaneous
Investing in the Unknown and Unknowable (Richard Zeckhauser)
Seven Immutable Laws of Investing
Flaws of Finance
What Goes Up Must Come Down
Aswath Damodaran Resources
Value Investing and Behavioral Finance
Damodaran on DCF
Why Do Investors Trade Too Much
Behavioral Finance (Tilson)
Are Investors Reluctant To Realise Their Losses
Towards a Science of Security Analysis
The Agile Manager’s Guide to Understanding Financial Statements
What Has Worked In Investing
Measuring The Moat
Why Value Investing Works So Well
The Wisdom of Great Investors
Identifying and Investing In High Quality Small-Cap Companies
Use of Historical Financial Statements to Separate Winners from Losers
Valuation Ratios and the Long-Run Stock Market Outlook
Insights From A Meeting With Mr. Greenblatt
Gannon on Investing
Investment Checklist

Safal Niveshak Book Reviews
The Little Book that Builds Wealth (Pat Dorsey)
Quality of Earnings (Thornton L. O’Glove)
One Up on Wall Street (Peter Lynch)

Quantitative Value Investing Lecture Video; Cartoon Book on Why an Economy Grows

Quantitative Value Investing

Money Ball: To get into the mood of quantitative analysis view these short videos on baseball: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=xn7C6jgl0RI and http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=emwkhGjTWcY

Quant Value Investing: http://greenbackd.com/2012/08/31/presentation-to-uc-davis-mba-value-investing-class-on-quantitative-value-investing/

Also go to www.greenbackd.com

Why an Economy Grows

Thanks to a reader for this cartoon book on how-an-economy-grows

Third Avenue Fund 3Q Letter:TAVF_3Q_2012 Letter

 

Job or Wealth Creation. Economics in One Lesson and More

Economics in One Lesson

I highly recommend reading the book and/or view the video series on each lesson. It is common-sense economics. Many don’t see the secondary effects (a needed skill for investing!) of particular actions. Say you see a government building a bridge across a river–fantastic, you say because we need infrastructure. But what could individuals have done with their money instead? What products or services were foregone to build that bridge? I bet not 1 in 100,000 thinks of that. YOU will.

The Book: economics_in_one_lesson_hazlitt   RECOMMENDED!

Video Series of Economic in One Lesson: http://archive.mises.org/14406/economics-in-one-lesson-the-video-series/

I will pay someone to find a better introductory book on basic, common-sense economics.

Economic Primers:

Intro to Austrian Economics by Taylor

lessons_for_the_young_economist_murphy

Essentials of Economics by Faustino Ballve

A more advanced exposition:Foundations of the Market Price System

If you don’t grasp economic principles (especially micro-economics) then investing successfully will be a Herculean task.

More jobs or wealth?

http://www.nytimes.com/2012/08/31/business/majority-of-new-jobs-pay-low-wages-study-finds.html?_r=2&hp

August 30, 2012

By CATHERINE RAMPELL

While a majority of jobs lost during the downturn were in the middle range of wages, a majority of those added during the recovery have been low paying, according to a new report from the National Employment Law Project.

The disappearance of mid-wage, mid-skill jobs is part of a longer-term trend that some refer to as a hollowing out of the work force, though it has probably been accelerated by government layoffs.

The overarching message here is we don’t just have a jobs deficit; we have a ‘good jobs’ deficit,” said Annette Bernhardt, the report’s author and a policy co-director at the National Employment Law Project, a liberal research and advocacy group.

The report looked at 366 occupations tracked by the Labor Department and clumped them into three equal groups by wage, with each representing a third of American employment in 2008. The middle third — occupations in fields like construction, manufacturing and information, with median hourly wages of $13.84 to $21.13 — accounted for 60 percent of job losses from the beginning of 2008 to early 2010.

The job market has turned around since then, but those fields have represented only 22 percent of total job growth. Higher-wage occupations — those with a median wage of $21.14 to $54.55 — represented 19 percent of job losses when employment was falling, and 20 percent of job gains when employment began growing again.

Lower-wage occupations, with median hourly wages of $7.69 to $13.83, accounted for 21 percent of job losses during the retraction. Since employment started expanding, they have accounted for 58 percent of all job growth.

The occupations with the fastest growth were retail sales (at a median wage of $10.97 an hour) and food preparation workers ($9.04 an hour). Each category has grown by more than 300,000 workers since June 2009.

Some of these new, lower-paying jobs are being taken by people just entering the labor force, like recent high school and college graduates. Many, though, are being filled by older workers who lost more lucrative jobs in the recession and were forced to take something to scrape by.

“I think I’ve been very resilient and resistant and optimistic, up until very recently,” said Ellen Pinney, 56, who was dismissed from a $75,000-a-year job in which she managed procurement and supply for an electronics company in March 2008.

Since then, she has cobbled together a series of temporary jobs in retail and home health care and worked as a part-time receptionist for a beauty salon. She is now working as an unpaid intern for a construction company, putting together bids and business plans for green energy projects, and has moved in with her 86-year-old father in Forked River, N.J.

“I really can’t bear it anymore,” she said, noting that her applications to places like PetSmart and Target had gone unanswered. “From every standpoint — my independence, my sense of purposefulness, my self-esteem, my life planning — this is just not what I was planning.”

As Ms. Pinney’s experience shows, low-wage jobs have not been growing especially quickly in this recovery; they account for such a big share of job growth mostly because mid-wage job growth has been so slow.

Over the last few decades, the number of mid-wage, mid-skill jobs has stagnated or declined as employers chose to automate routine tasks or to move them offshore.

Job growth has been concentrated in positions that tend to fall into two categories: manual work that must be done in person, like styling hair or serving food, which usually pays relatively little; and more creative, design-oriented work like engineering or surgery, which often pays quite well.

Since 2001, employment has grown 8.7 percent in lower-wage occupations and 6.6 percent in high-wage ones. Over that period, mid wage occupation employment has fallen by 7.3 percent.

This “polarization” of skills and wages has been documented meticulously by David H. Autor, an economics professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. A recent study found that this polarization accelerated in the last three recessions, particularly the last one, as financial pressures forced companies to reorganize more quickly.

“This is not just a nice, smooth process,” said Henry E. Siu, an economics professor at the University of British Columbia, who helped write the recent study about polarization and the business cycle. “A lot of these jobs were suddenly wiped out during recession and are not coming back.”

On top of private sector revamps, state and local governments have been shedding workers in recent years. Those jobs lost in the public sector have been primarily in mid and higher-wage positions, according to Ms. Bernhardt’s analysis.

“Whenever you look at data like these, there is this tendency to get overwhelmed, that there are these inevitable, big macro forces causing this polarization and we can’t do anything about them. In fact, we can,” Ms. Bernhardt said. She called for more funds for states to stem losses in the public sector and federal infrastructure projects to employ idled construction workers. Both proposals have faced resistance from Republicans in Congress.  (Editor: More public work means more taxes; more taxes equal less production; and less production equals less wealth).

Dwight R. Lee

Creating Jobs vs. Creating Wealth

Remember the opportunity costs.

January 2000 • Volume: 50 • Issue: 1 •  20 comments

Government policies are commonly evaluated in terms of how many jobs they create. Restricting imports is seen as a way to protect and create domestic jobs. Tax preferences and loopholes are commonly justified as ways of increasing employment in the favored activity. Presidents point with pride to the number of jobs created in the economy during their administrations. Supposedly the more jobs created the more successful the administration. There probably has never been a government spending program whose advocates failed to mention that it creates jobs. Even wars are seen as coming with the silver lining of job creation.

Now there is nothing wrong with job creation. Working in jobs is an important way people create wealth. So the emphasis on job creation is an understandable one. But it is easy for people to forget that creating more wealth is what we really want to accomplish, and jobs are merely a means to that end. (How about having people paid for building sand castles during low tides—infinite work?) When that elementary fact is forgotten, people are easily duped by arguments that elevate creation of jobs to an end in itself. While these arguments may sound plausible, they are used to support policies that destroy wealth rather than create it. I shall consider a few of the depressingly many examples in this column and the next.

Creating Jobs Is Not the Problem

The purpose of all economic activity is to produce as much value as possible with the scarce resources (including human effort) available. But no matter how far we push back the limits of scarcity, those limits are never vanquished. Scarcity will forever prevent us from securing all the things we desire. There will always be jobs to do far more than can ever be done. So creating jobs is not the problem. The problem is creating jobs in which people produce the most value. This is the point of the apocryphal story of an engineer who, while visiting China, came across a large crew of men building a dam with picks and shovels. When the engineer pointed out to the supervisor that the job could be completed in a few days, rather than many months, if the men were given motorized earthmoving equipment, the supervisor said that such equipment would destroy many jobs. “Oh,” the engineer responded, “I thought you were interested in building a dam. If it’s more jobs you want, why don’t you have your men use spoons instead of shovels.”

As I tell my students at the University of Georgia, I will employ every person in our college town of Athens if they’ll only work for me cheaply enough, say a nickel a month. Lower the wage a bit more and I’ll hire everyone in the entire state of Georgia. If I hired workers at those wages, I could make a profit having them build dams with spoons. Of course, the students recognize that my offer is silly since they can make far more working for other employers, which reflects the more important reason my offer is silly: concentrating on the number of jobs ignores the value being created, or not created. More value will be produced in the higher-paying jobs my students can get than in the ones I am offering. A big advantage realized from the wages that emerge in open labor markets is that they attract people into not just any employment, but into their highest-valued employment.

Another advantage of market wages is that they force employers to consider the opportunity cost of hiring workers their value in alternative jobs and to remain constantly alert for ways to eliminate jobs by creating the same value with fewer workers. All economic progress results from being able to provide the same, or improved, goods and services with fewer workers, thus eliminating some jobs and freeing up labor to increase production in new, more productive jobs. The failure to understand this source of increasing prosperity explains the widespread sympathy with destructive public policies.

Dynamiting Our Way to More Jobs

In the 1840s a French politician seriously advocated blowing up the tracks at Bordeaux on the railroad from Paris to Spain to create more jobs in Bordeaux. Freight would have to be moved from one train to another and passengers would require hotels, all of which would mean more jobs. (This proposal was discussed and demolished by the nineteenth-century economist and essayist Frederic Bastiat in Economic Sophisms, pp. 94-95, available from FEE.)

This proposal is even more absurd than my offer to hire people for a nickel a month. At least I would employ workers to produce something of value, rather than to partially undo damage that is inflicted needlessly. Unfortunately, absurdity does not prevent economically destructive policies from being proposed and implemented. Using the jobs-creation justification, politicians commonly enact legislation that increases the effort required to produce a given amount of value.

One of the arguments for restricting imports is that it will create (or protect) domestic jobs. True, it will create some domestic jobs, just as destroying a section of a rail line will create domestic jobs. But also like a break in a rail line, import restrictions make it more costly to obtain valuable products. The only reason a country imports products is that it is the cheapest way to acquire them; it takes fewer workers to obtain the imported products through foreign trade than by producing them directly. In this way trade is like a technological advance, freeing up workers and allowing them to increase the production of goods and services available for consumption. Import restrictions create jobs in the same way dynamiting our railroads, bombing our factories, and requiring that workers use shovels instead of modern earth-moving equipment would create jobs. Always keep in mind that creating jobs is a means to the ultimate end of economic activity, which is creating wealth.

Creating Government Jobs

Because people tend to think of jobs as ends rather than means, they are easily fooled into supporting government programs on grounds that jobs will be created. We have all heard people argue in favor of military bases, highway construction, and environmental regulations on business on these grounds. To justify spending, government agencies commonly perform benefit/cost studies in which the jobs created are counted as benefits. This is like counting the hours you work to earn enough money to buy a car as one of the car’s benefits. The jobs created by a government project represent a cost of the project: the opportunity cost. The workers employed in government activities could be producing value doing something else. The relevant question is not whether a government project creates jobs, but whether the workers in those jobs will create more wealth than they would in other jobs. This is a question advocates of government programs don’t want asked. If it were, there would be far fewer low-productivity government jobs and far more high-productivity private-sector jobs.